Home > Employment, Europe, Federal Reserve, Government, Politics > Promising Isn’t The Same As Delivering

Promising Isn’t The Same As Delivering

Yet another weekend appears to be poised to end without the promised big-picture agreement on Greek debt. The BBC was reporting earlier today that talks between the Greek Prime Minister and the leaders of other coalition parties had concluded without agreement to take additional austerity measures; at this hour Bloomberg is reporting that there is agreement on cuts of 1.5% of GDP although these will not be finalized until Monday. These Greek-on-Greek talks became necessary because European Union representatives demanded additional austerity measures. On Friday, a report from Radio Netherlands Worldwide said that the AAA countries demanded “that the [Greek] government implement agreed reforms and austerity measures by March at the latest. Otherwise they will withdraw the bailout funds pledged last year.”

In case you’re wondering: yes, when those bailout funds were announced last year the stock market rallied because the problem had been solved. You see, it is easy to announce the desire to help. It is harder to actually help.

I wonder if the U.S. will consider throwing in a little help now that we have had a couple of months of decent data (more on that in a moment). I think it would be a mistake, both politically and economically, but this Administration has tended to have a tin ear politically since taking office. A driving force of its foreign policy has been a desire to be loved worldwide, and it would not surprise me a bit if we started to hear about the U.S. taking a bigger role in talks. Would this be bullish or bearish for our markets? It might be bullish since it would increase the perceived chance of the immediate crisis being averted, but it might be considered bearish since it increases the chance of a crisis later. It would, though, change the equation significantly since the U.S. is the only power capable of writing a hundred-billion-dollar check alone (heck, that’s only a tenth of a trillion!). I imagine the stock market would like it but I’m pretty sure the bond market would hate it.

This wasn’t even a consideration a couple of months ago, when we had enough of our own problems to deal with. Those problems are still here, but the problems we have – high private leverage, a chastened although recovering banking system, an addiction to extremely high budget deficits with little appetite to reduce the size of government, and a dangerously loose monetary policy – are not the problems that the Administration (and the Fed) believe we have. It is true that if the economy can grow at 4% for 5-7 years, many of our problems will diminish, but policymakers seem to think the weak growth is not an effect but rather a cause of our current circumstance. And recently, the news on growth has been better.

On Friday, the Employment Report produced a new jobs figure of 243k, which was about 100k greater than expectations. The Unemployment Rate dropped to 8.263%, only a whisker away from triple-downticking. Aggregate hours worked and average hourly earnings both rose, which means that Q1 income got off to a good start.

The January report is a little quirky, partly because of the usual seasonal adjustment issues around year-end and partly because benchmark revisions take place in this month. I’m not terribly uncomfortable with the overall reading of mild strength, because it’s consistent with most other labor market indicators showing the same thing. (In my mind, the question is more about sustainability of this mild strength if Europe holds to current trends.) The Unemployment Rate plunge was on the quirky side because the Household Survey from which it is derived incorporated the annual adjustment to population.[1] According to the BLS, the adjustment “increased the estimated size of the of the civilian noninstitutional population in December by 1,510,000, the civilian labor force by 258,000, employment by 216,000, unemployment by 42,000, and persons not in the labor force by 1,252,000.” Overall, however, the civilian labor force grew by 508k and employment by 847k, which means that the addition from other than the population adjustment was 250k to the civilian labor force and 631k to employment. That’s quite a large number, and won’t do anything to soothe those who think that every number is a government conspiracy. But, as I said, it’s not inconsistent with other signs of decent employment growth.

On the unfortunate side, the participation rate plunged to 63.7%, the lowest since 1983 (see Chart, source Bloomberg). The BLS explained this by saying “This was because the population increase was primarily among persons 55 and older and, to a lesser degree, persons 16 to 24 years of age. Both these age groups have lower levels of labor force participation than the general population.” However, notice that while this explains the sudden drop, what it means is that the prior ratio was overstated, not that the current ratio is understated. So this is something less than encouraging.

On this point, Julia Coronado at BNP (whose analysis of economic releases is generally among the more clear-eyed reads) made a great summary observation. She said “It is becoming increasingly likely that the path toward lower unemployment rates will mainly be through fewer workers rather than an acceleration in job growth.” Since economic output is workers times hours worked times productivity, this means the path to a full recovery in economic output is either going to be longer hours or an acceleration in productivity. That’s really the path we’re going to be on for a long time hence, now that the baby boom generation is beginning to be of retirement age. And if I may say so, it is a prime argument for allocating more GDP to the private sector, where productivity enhancements are generally developed, and less to the public sector. The government can keep redistributing the pie, but it would be better to grow the pie and government has had an abysmal record at doing so for roughly the last eight thousand years. We could hope for a better result in the future, but to do so would seem audacious.

Another growth sign from Friday were good as well. Non-manufacturing ISM reached an 11-month high at 56.8, far above estimates. All of this news helped push stock prices 1.5% higher, commodities prices 0.8% higher (despite a 1.1% fall in Precious Metals), and 10-year yields 10bps higher to 1.92%. Even TIPS yields rose, finally, by 8bps at the 10-year point.

In other inflation-bond-related news, Japan is reportedly considering a re-start of its inflation-linked debt market. As I illustrated recently, Japan’s inflation rate has been rising since early 2010, and as the tsunami effects finish passing through the system the core rate will likely rise to above zero and end the nation’s deflationary period. The last Japanese inflation-linked bond was issued in June 2008 when year-on-year core CPI was +0.2% but large investor losses in illiquid Japanese inflation markets in late 2008 combined with a plunge of core inflation to -1.6% in early 2010 meant the Ministry of Finance feared there would be scant demand for the bonds, which unlike those in other countries never carried a ‘par floor’ (so, in the case of persistent deflation, you could get back less than you invested in nominal terms).

That structure detail annoyed bond salesmen, but it is the right treatment. Otherwise, investors get a free option on deflation that means their real return will rise in a deflationary environment although it is constant at any positive level of inflation. That turns out to be painful to model, and awkward to trade, as asset-swappers learned to their/our chagrin in 2008. Having said all of that, I expect there will be a strong sentiment to add such a floor to the JGBi when and if the program re-starts.

On Monday, most of the day in the U.S. will be occupied with discussing the Super Bowl. But be aware that St. Louis Fed President Bullard will be speaking in Chicago at 8:55ET on the topic of inflation targeting. Listen carefully for any intimation that the Fed is trying to generate support for a policy of price level targeting as opposed to inflation rate targeting. I wrote way back in December 2010 about the Fed Chairman’s affection for inflation targeting, some of his prior words on the subject, and of the (better) arguments of KC Fed economist George Kahn. It’s worth a review if the topic comes up again. In the current context, whipping up a fresh discussion of price-level targeting would be another excuse to let inflation keep accelerating for a while. Under a price-level target, the Fed just promises to hit the price-level target on some future date, implying an average level of inflation between now and then. So, if for example the Fed wanted to run inflation a little faster right now, it could do so and pretend that this didn’t impair their credibility as long as they eventually hit that target.

I think the FOMC is looking carefully for ways to let inflation run faster without the bond market charging higher rates for that policy. If they can somehow convince investors that the 10-year average inflation will be 2%, even if it happens to be 3-4% over the next, say, 3-4 years, then 10-year nominal rates would stay down and real rates very negative despite an inflationary policy. I doubt they can pull it off, because I don’t think they have much credibility as it is. And, as Kahn pointed out in 2009, “[central banks] have no modern practical experience with such targets.”

The lack of practical experience, however, has never stopped this Fed before. I continue to marvel that investors are willing to be long rates here. You see, it is easy to announce the desire to price-level target. It is harder to actually price-level target.


[1] The BLS recognizes that the nation adds these citizens over the course of the year, but rather than make monthly estimates of labor force growth it adds them all at once in January. This year, the jump is large partly because it reflects the results of the decennial Census, which marks the actual population to the estimated population as of 2010.

  1. onebir
    February 6, 2012 at 3:31 am

    Re the NFP ‘beat’ there’s a reason to distrust it that I haven’t seen discussed anywhere. 2-3 million people get fired/laid off, or quit to seek new work or retire every year in January vs the number that worked in November.

    But people are inhibited from quitting or retiring by the poor state of the job market. This change will have started – and quite likely worsened – in the last couple of years. But Seasonal factors use filters that incorporate quite a few years data – I think 5-6 with Census X-11/12: they can’t cope with sharp changes in seasonality (& tend to lag even gradual changes in seasonality).

    So the seasonal factor, although it doesn’t show signs of deliberate manipulation, implicitly incorporates a behavioural assumption that’s out of date. And the Jan seasonality likely adds back too many jobs to reflect ‘normal’ voluntary separations.

    The seasonality of involuntary separations may also have changed. In good times, I’d imagine firms would be very reluctant to lay people off from Thanksgiving through New Year, due to the effect on the morale of retained workers. But in a weak labour market, when workers feel lucky to have jobs, and under financial stress, these kinds of delays are less likely.

    This also suggests the +ve seasonal adjustment in Jan is too big (but this time with offsets in Nov & Dec).

    • February 6, 2012 at 7:25 am

      Yeah, I’m sure there are seasonal adjustment problems here. I think the number is probably too strong overall given the underlying strength (or lack of it). And thank you for presenting some good candidates for that! Relying on employment data in January is problematic. On the other hand, though, there is a broad consistency across several sorts of data. Initial Claims (while suspect) has been broadly better. Consumer Confidence ‘Jobs Hard to Get’ ticked up this month, but is still doing better than it has over the past year. The Unemployment Rate improvement is certainly overstated, but it HAS improved. None of these show a LOT of strength, but nor do they show weakness. I suspect the true run rate of jobs additions is maybe 150k. If it was much faster than that, we’d see the Consumer Confidence numbers doing better. But 150k/month would represent a slowly growing economy, although not one strong enough to survive too much turbulence.

  1. No trackbacks yet.

Leave a Reply to Michael AshtonCancel reply

Discover more from E-piphany

Subscribe now to keep reading and get access to the full archive.

Continue reading