Shooting Blanks
Almost eight years after the bankruptcy filing of Lehman Brothers and the first of many central bank quantitative easing programs, it appears the expansion – the weakest on record by several measures – is petering out. The Q2 growth rate of GDP was 1.2% annualized, meaning that the last three quarters were +0.9%, +0.8%, +1.2%. That’s not a recession, but it’s also not an expansion to write home about.
But why? Why after all of the quantitative easing? Is the effectiveness waning? Is it time for more?
I read recently about how many economists are expecting the Bank of England to increase asset purchases (QE) this Thursday in an attempt to counteract the depressing effects of Brexit on growth. Some think the increase will be as much as £150 billion. That’s impressive, but will it help?
I also read recently about how the Bank of Japan “disappointed investors” by not increasing asset purchases except incrementally. The analysts said this was disappointing because the BOJ’s action was “not enough to cause growth.”
That’s because no amount of money printing is enough to cause growth. No amount.
It seems like people get confused with this concept, including many economists, because we use units of currency. So let’s try illustrating the point a different way. Suppose I pay you in candy bars for the widgets you produce. Suppose I pay you 10 candy bars, each of which is 10 ounces, for each widget. Now, if I start paying you 11 candy bars instead of 10, then the price has risen and you want to produce more widgets, right? This, indirectly, is what economists are thinking when they think about the effect of monetary policy.
But suppose that I pay you 11 candy bars, but now each candy bar is 9.1 ounces instead of 10 ounces? I suspect you will not be fooled into producing more widgets. You will realize that I am still paying you 100 ounces of candy per widget. You are not fooled by the fact that the unit of account changed in intrinsic value.
Now, when the central bank adds to the money supply, but doesn’t change the amount of stuff the economy produces (they don’t have the power to direct production!), then all that changes is the size of the unit of account – the candy bar, or in this case the dollar – and the number of dollars you need to buy a widget goes up. That’s called inflation. And the only way that printing more money can cause production to increase is if you don’t notice that the value of any given unit of currency has declined. That is, only if I say I’m paying you 11 candy bars – but you haven’t noticed they are smaller – will you respond to the change in terms. This is called “money illusion,” and it is why money printing does not cause growth in theory…and, as it turns out, in practice.[1]
There is nothing terribly strange or unpredictable about what is going on in global growth in terms of the response to monetary policy. The only thing strange is that eight years on, with numerous observations on which to evaluate the efficacy of quantitative easing, the conclusion appears to be that it might not be quite as effective as policymakers had thought. And therefore, we need to do lots more of it, the thought process seems to go. But anything times zero is zero. Central banks are not shooting an inaccurate, awkward weapon in the fight to stimulate growth, which just needs to be fired a lot more so that something eventually hits. They are shooting blanks. And no amount of shooting blanks will bring down the bad guy.
[1] I address this aspect of money, and other aspects that affect inflation, in my book What’s Wrong With Money: The Biggest Bubble of All.
Hi,
QE->Growth is a shortcut. Isn’t QE meant to boost growth through the effect of cheaper credit? QE helps to lower long term rates (or at least accelerate their fall). That in turns could help growth through more demand for credit. So, if we consider what is the transmission mechanism that is not working “as planned”, isn’t it credit demand?
Cheers, Philippe.
>
It would be, if the market interest rate wasn’t a ‘clearing’ rate. Obviously every rate has a payer and a receiver; there’s only a gain if a project is undertaken such that the gain to the receiver at least equals his other investment opportunities AND the loss to the payer is exceeded by the project value. But if the market was clearing, one of these two things isn’t true at a disequilibrium. In fact, the Fed clearly pointed to its “portfolio balance channel,” by which they meant (and they stated this) that by removing lower risk securities from the market they forced lenders/investors to take on more risk than they wanted by buying riskier securities (or the same securities at lower rates). That would work IF there were stranded, high-value projects for which credit was not available at any price. Otherwise, it just allows lower-value projects to be undertaken, whose gain is not balanced by the loss of the investors who lose through the “portfolio balance channel” of having an investment mix they don’t like.
The only way that interest rate policy “works” is if there is a market inefficiency so that the market wasn’t clearing. It could be argued that for QE1, this may have been the case because banks were undercapitalized (although there were other lenders). But it’s hard to argue for most of the rest of QE.
The Fed acts like the market-clearing interest rate isn’t “special” in any way. But it is VERY special! It is the one that balances the gain to the borrowers and the gain to the lenders such that the total value to the economy is maximized given preferences. Good question!
Furthermore, QE replaces T-securities with lower-yielding reserves. Thus the direct immediate impact is to reduce private sector income – no wonder it is not stimulative!
The indirect effects which you explain may well be offsetting but, to your point, an overall positive effect is difficult to find.