Why So Negative?
The news on Friday that the Bank of Japan had joined the ECB in pushing policy rates negative was absorbed with brilliant enthusiasm on Wall Street. At least, much of the attribution for the exceptional rally was given to the BoJ’s move. I find it implausible, arguably silly, to think that a marginal change in monetary policy by a desperate central bank on the other side of the world – however unexpected – would have a massive effect on US stocks. Subsequent trading, which has reversed almost all of that ebullience in two days, suggests that other investors also may agree that just maybe the sorry state of earnings growth rates in this country, combined with a poor economic outlook and still-lofty valuations, should matter more than Kuroda’s gambit.
To be sure, this is a refrain that Ben Bernanke (remember him? Of helicopter infamy?) was singing last month, before the Federal Reserve hiked rates impotently, and clearly the Fed is investigating whether negative rates is a “tool” they should add to their oh-so-expansive toolbox for fighting deflation.
Scratch that. The Fed no longer needs to fight deflation; inflation is at 2.4% and rising. The toolbox the Fed is interested in adding to is the one that contains the tools for goosing growth. That toolbox, judging from historical success rates, is virtually empty. And always has been.
Back to Japan: let me point out that if the BOJ goal has been to extinguish deflation, it has already done so. The chart below (source: Bloomberg) shows core inflation in Japan for the last 20 years or so. Abstracting from the sales-tax-related spike, core inflation has risen fairly steadily from -1.5% to near 1.0% since mid-2010.
They did this, very simply, by working to accelerate money supply growth from the 1.5%-2.0% growth that was the standard in the late pre-crisis period to over 4% by 2014 and 2015 (see chart, source: Bloomberg).
Not rocket science, folks. Monetary science.
Now, recently money supply growth has begun to fall off, so the BoJ likely was concerned by that and wants to find a way to ensure that inflation doesn’t slip back. If that was their intention, then cutting rates was exactly the wrong thing to do. The regression below (source: Bloomberg) illustrates in a different way what I have shown here before: interest rates and money velocity are closely tied (as Friedman explained decades ago). The r-squared of this relationship – assuming that functionally a linear fit is appropriate, which I am not sure of – is a heady 0.822.
You may notice the data is from the US; that’s because Bloomberg doesn’t have a good velocity series for Japan’s M2 but the causal relationship is the same: lower term interest rates imply less reason not to hold cash.
Now, it may be the case that this relationship ceases to apply at negative rates even though the idea is based on the relative difference between cash yielding zero and longer-term investments or consumption alternatives. The reason that velocity might behave differently at sub-zero rates is that people respond asymmetrically to losses and gains. That is, the pleasure of a gain is dominated by the pain of the same-sized loss, in most people. This cognitive bias may cause savers/investors to behave strikingly different if they are charged for deposits than if they are merely paid zero on those deposits (even if zero is lower than other available rates). In that case, we might see a spike in money velocity once rates go through zero as cash balances become hot-potatoes, just as if investment opportunities suddenly appeared. And rates, not just overnight but term rates, just went negative in Japan. The chart below (source: Bloomberg) shows the 5y JGB rate.
Several observations:
- The speculation that sub-zero rates might cause a rise in velocity is just that: speculation. There’s no data to suggest that this effect exists.
- Frankly, I suspect it doesn’t, but it’s possible. However, if it does I would expect it to be a spot discontinuity in the relationship between rates and velocity. That is, the behavior should change between 0% and some negative rate, but then be somewhat linear thereafter. Cognitively, the reaction is both a general loss aversion, which is linear but no different at negative rates from zero, and a behavioral “endowment” reaction that is to the “taking” of money from a person and not necessarily related to the size of the theft.
- If it does exist, it still doesn’t mean that cutting rates to a negative rate was wise. After all, quantitative easing has done a fine job of pushing up inflation, and so there is no reason to take a speculative gamble like this to keep inflation moving higher. Just do more of the same. Lots more.
- More likely, the BoJ is doing this because they believe that negative rates will stimulate growth. This is much more speculative than you might think, and I may be overgenerous in phrasing the point that way. In any case, any growth benefit would stem either from weakening the currency (which QE would also do, with less risk) or from provoking investment in more marginal ventures that become acceptable at lower financing rates. We call that malinvestment, and it isn’t a good thing.
- Whatever the point of the BoJ’s move, the size of any growth effect from currency reactions is utterly dependent on the reaction function of trading counterparties. If other countries seek to devalue their currencies as well, then the whole operation will be inert.
So, will the BoJ’s move save US stocks? Heck, it won’t even save the Japanese economy.
Hi Michael, I have been following Japan (and been short JPY for yearssss) and keep being amazed how far QQE has been pushed. I am sure you have read John Hussman’s Weekly comments (like ’16 cents’) also and he recently wrote about Japan. The relationship between short-term interest rates,velocity & reserves is a very strong one but I wonder if you had any thoughts on how an exogenous shock could suddenly derail it. I find it impossible to believe the BoJ could extend it’s QQE and grow its balance sheet at infinitum without -at some point- affecting confidence in itself, the Yen & the system. In 2017 the BoJ’s balance sheet will = GDP; at any point in time someone has to hold all these excess reserves JPY. Will there come a point where the system is so saturated that V goes up in the form of a JPY crash which could snowball into inflation which will accelerate the cash dump/hot potato. Have you got any views when or what could cause a collapse in confidence (hot potato) and send V through the roof? Kind RegardsJR Sent from S/Y Atlas Shruggedhttp://blog.mailasail.com/atlasshrugged
Date: Wed, 3 Feb 2016 00:27:37 +0000 To: janrobyns@hotmail.com
Hi Jan – The whole trick to creating inflation is to create a little bit without kicking off a vicious process. But the vicious process (inflation up — > causes interest rates to rise — > causes velocity to rise — > causes inflation to rise) is a real danger even if the system doesn’t break. I think that’s the situation you’re talking about, but there’s the risk of a sudden break in confidence.
I talk about this in the book I have coming out in March from Wiley (“What’s Wrong with Money”, available for pre-order now!). Money, when it fails, fails either slowly, quickly, or slowly and then quickly. If inflation comes back slowly, then the BOJ (and the Fed, and the ECB) are in a bit of a pickle since they aren’t operating on the margin any more and can’t reasonably pull back the balance sheet fast enough to affect the money growth metrics. But it’s not a disaster situation. However, especially in the case of Japan the risk is that inflation leads to a break in confidence in the currency and a run for the exits. In some sense that’s long overdue; when that happens you’re talking about mild hyperinflation (and that’s my “slowly, then quickly” scenario) and it’s hard to recover from. At that point, inflation ceases to be a monetary phenomenon and becomes a broken-money phenomenon. It would not surprise me at all to see Japan end up there one day.